A general equilibrium covers all consumers and firms
A partial equilibrium uses just 1 consumer and 1 form who maximise utility and profit based on a given budget set
we use a very simple set up with 1 organisation and 1 firm when we would ideally use all of them
In consumer theory, consumers exchange their budget/position for a more optimalallocation
In an exchange economy, there are N agents, summed to i, and L goods, summed to j
We simplify the exchange economy to 2 people (agents) and 2 goods
The gradient of an indifference curve is the MRS
Society involves all the consumers involved in the model
An edgeworth box represents the total endowment of each good
In an edgeworth box, one consumer starts in the bottom left, and the other starts from the top right, so both their endowment points are at the same place
A good allocation is within the edgeworth box, and will depend on the criteria used
Pareto efficient allocation involves a point that cannot be changed to improve both parties
Pareto efficient allocation occurs when the two indifference curves just touch eachother, so are tangent
Marshallian allocation finds optimal solutions based on the process of goods and consumersbudget set
marshillian allocation maximises utility subject to budget constraints for each consumer
The budget constraint is the value of endowment
A competitive equilibrium is a pair of prices and allocations where allocations are optimal given the prices, and markets clear at the prices
Market clearing bans total demand is equal to totalsupply
Competitive equilibrium is Walrasian
The competitive/ walrasian equilibrium may not be unique
The first theorem of welfare economics states that the equilibrium point is efficient because both parties maximise with respect to price
The second theorem of welfare economics is that you can get equilibrium with an efficient outcome
The edgeworth box allocation can also be justified using game theory and finding the CORE allocation
for price related optimisation, you set P2 as 1, and P1 as P, as it is the price of good 1 if good 2 costs £1
when solving price optomisation, you get the allocation and prices of the 2 goods. However, the prices are relative, and involves setting one of the prices as a numeraire (equal to 1)