Save
Economics semester 2
Lecture 1
Save
Share
Learn
Content
Leaderboard
Share
Learn
Created by
Elanor Warner
Visit profile
Cards (38)
Perfect
Competition as the industry benchmark
Large
number of
firms
each of which has no market power
Homogenous
products
LRAC
is small in relation to market demand
All firms are
'price
takers'
View source
Perfect
Competition as the industry benchmark
Perfect information among consumers and producers
Exit and entry are
costless
Firms
maximise
profits subject to given cost conditions
There is
no
competition in perfect competition
View source
P
= MC in a
perfectly competitive
industry
View source
Allocative efficiency
The price that consumers pay for one unit of a product is equal to the
marginal cost
of production
View source
Allocative efficiency
is a 'first best' outcome because it maximises
social welfare
View source
Allocative efficiency
is a fundamental requirement of
Pareto efficiency
View source
Only
perfectly
competitive
industries automatically generate the P = MC outcome
View source
P
= MC means that firms only earn 'normal profits' and there is
no
economic rent
View source
Lerner
index
Fundamental concept in analysis of industries,
P-MC/p = 1/n
where the term on the lhs is the price-cost markup, and the term on the rhs is the inverse of price elasticity of demand
n = dQ/dP . P/Q
note: slope only partly determines n
View source
Interpretation of learner index: price cost mark-up (determined by industry structure), is a function of price elasticity of demand
The Lerner index ranges from 0 to 1
View source
In
a perfectly competitive industry, the Lerner index =
0
View source
In
a pure monopoly, the Lerner index =
1
View source
Structure
-Conduct-Performance paradigm
Simple
model: S → C → P, with uni-directional causality
Structure: How
concentrated
is the industry?
Conduct
:
Profit maximisation
Performance: P =
MC
(allocative efficiency),
productive
efficiency, R&D
View source
The 'simple' SCP model only makes sense when causation is
unidirectional
View source
CR5
, CR3
Concentration ratios
that measure the
market share
of the five and three biggest firms, respectively
View source
CR5 and
CR3
only include the biggest
firms
and do not take account of differences in the shares of the 'N' biggest firms
View source
Concentration measure
Needs to take account of: 1. Number of
firms
(N), 2.
Inequality
in market shares (I), C = c (N, I)
View source
Industry A
The 5 biggest firms account for
100
% of the market, and all firms have
equal
shares
View source
Industry B
10 firms, but the biggest firm is
10x
the size of the
smallest
(0.5 v. 0.05)
View source
Industry C
10
firms, CR5 =
80
%
View source
Industry D
10 firms, CR5 =
50%
View source
In
terms of competitive strategy, industries A and D are likely to be the most competitive, while industry B is likely to be the
least
competitive
View source
Herfindahl
-Hirschman Index (HHI)
Where N is the total number of
firms
in the industry, and the share of each firm is squared, and this is summed for all
firms
View source
A
pure monopoly has an
HHI
= 1
View source
The minimum value of the HHI is
1/N
, which means all N firms in the industry have
identical market shares
View source
Using
HHI, the rank order of industry concentration is: B (
0.28
), A (0.2), C (0.13), and D (0.1)
View source
One disadvantage of the
HHI
is that it requires
firm level
data for all firms, which is very difficult/impossible to obtain
View source
Simple
model
Offers clear
guidance
to policy makers
Competitive industries are 'good' for
social welfare
Concentrated industries are 'bad' for
social welfare
View source
Alternative
specifications of SCP
Do not yield
clear
guidance
Requires
trade-offs
Possibly
acceptance
of second-best outcomes
View source
Monotonically decreasing average costs
Larger firms have an
absolute
cost advantage, so
'natural
monopolies'
View source
Trade
-off between
Allocative
efficiency and
productive
efficiency
View source
Government intervention
on pricing
View source
Asymmetric
information
View source
Concentration measure (1)
CR, or
CR3
, which measure the
market share
of the five and three biggest firms, respectively
View source
In empirical economics, it is common to use CRs, or
CR3
, which measure the
market share
of the five and three biggest firms, respectively
View source
Standard
Industrial Classification (SIC) entries
In the
UK
View source
This
metric only includes the
biggest firms
and, more importantly, it does not take account of differences in the shares of the 'N' biggest firms
View source
Note: we are interested in
industry
concentration, not
aggregate
concentration
View source