Intercept for RF1 occurs when P2 = 0 (but costs >0); likewise, RF2 occurs when P2 = 0 (but costs >0)
P>MC in Bertrand model with differentiated products
Equilibrium yields P1* and P2*
No requirement that P1 = P2 (brand loyalty)
Strategic complements (positive cross price elasticity of demand);
Consumers have finite budgets
Only purchase a finite bundle of characteristics;
analysis is farmed in terms of an efficiency frontier (‘budget constraint’), and product space
Two characteristics:
a1 and a2 (e.g. if dealing with breakfast cereals, first characteristic is calories and the second characteristic is vitamin content), each brand varies according to proportion of these two characteristics
If have £1 to spend on brand 1: a1 = 100(1/10) = 10, a2 = 20(1/10) = 2
For brand 2, a1 = 56 (1/8) = 7, a2 = 56 (1/8) = 7
For brand 3, a1 = 12(1/6) = 2, a2 = 60(1/6) = 0
Efficiency frontier
Any point inside this frontier are inefficient
Frontier is horizontal to axis at x3 as no other brands more than a2
Brands 1 & 2 are ‘neighbours’ as are brands 2 & 3 but brands 1 & 3 are not ‘neighbours’
Brand
Assume ’brand n’ is introduced to market, either by new or existing firm
Brand N is comprised of different ratios of a1 and a2 compared to existing brands (slope ray is different)
If brand N is supplied at too high price it will be uncompetitive because inefficient as;
As price N is reduced, we expand long the vector to N1, where N becomes efficient
As price declines further, expand on vector to N2
N2 offers same amount of a1 compared to brand 1, and more of a2, therefore dominates brand 1 (leaves market)
N captures all of Brand 1’s market share and half between N and Brand 2
Further price fall of Brand N
As price falls further to N3 (dotted line), brand 2 becomes inefficient, and brands N and 3 become neighbours
At even lower prices (beyond dotted line through x3), brand 3 becomes inefficient and brand N monopolises the market;
also suggests discontinuities in the demand curve for a particular brand as the process of rival brands change;
Also consider whether we allow consumers to mix existing combinations of characteristics to achieve their ‘optimal’ ratio
Models of horizontal product differentiation - spatial interpretation:
Hosteling ‘Linear City’
Geographical location is the characteristics that differentiates suppliers;
The city is a straight line, bounded at each end
Customers are uniformly distributed along the city
Vendors charge the same price for an identical product
Px = Pc + Tx
Pc = production cost
Tx = transport cost (function of consumer distance from vendor)
Locations A & B minimisation average travel distance (Tx), for all consumers
Locations A & B are not optimal for either vendor
Optimal location for both vendors is not optimal for consumers
Competition determines geographical location
Salop and circular city
Consumers uniformly distributed in this city, unlike hotel long there are no ‘end points’ in this city (circle). Firms aims to locate as far away as possible from rivals
If circumference is standardised to 1, and the number of firms is N, optimal distance between each firm is 1/N
4 identical restaurants in thus city
1/4 miles between each, if consumers evenly distributed then max one-way trip is 1/8 mile (1/4 for round trip)
They derive utility according to: u.(t-p) where a consumer with income t, derives utility from consuming one unit of a product of quality level u, at a price, t
Consumers partition themselves by income, such that brands of successively higher quality are purchased by consumers in successively higher income brackets