1.4.1 Government intervention

Cards (33)

  • Why do governments interveneProviding healthcare and education, which the free market would underprovide
    • To correct market failures
  • Indirect taxes
    Taxes on expenditure that increase production costs for producers, so producers supply less, increasing market price and reducing demand
  • Indirect taxes
    • £1 tax per packet of cigarettes
  • Types of indirect taxes
    • Ad valorem taxes (e.g. VAT)
    • Specific taxes (e.g. fuel duty)
  • Ad valorem taxes
    Percentages, such as VAT, which adds 20% of the unit price
  • Incidence of ad valorem tax
    Depends on price elasticity of demand - for inelastic goods like cigarettes, consumers bear larger burden
  • Ad valorem taxes raise more revenue if demand is price inelastic, as demand falls only slightly with the tax
  • Specific taxes
    A set tax per unit, such as the 58p per litre fuel duty on unleaded petrol
  • Indirect taxes
    Could reduce quantity of demerit goods consumed by increasing price, internalising the externality
  • Subsidy
    A payment from the government to a producer to lower their costs of production and encourage them to produce more
  • Subsidies encourage the consumption of merit goods by including the full social benefit in the market price
  • Subsidies
    • Subsidising recycling schemes to make it cheaper for consumers to recycle waste
  • Maximum price

    A price set by the government where the consumption or production of a good is to be encouraged, below the free market price
  • Maximum prices prevent monopolies exploiting consumers, but could lead to government failure if the optimum price is misjudged
  • Maximum prices
    Can lead to welfare gains for consumers by keeping prices low, but may reduce firm profits and investment in the long run
  • Minimum price

    A price set by the government where the consumption or production of a good is to be discouraged, above the free market price
  • Minimum prices
    • Minimum price on alcohol, National Minimum Wage
  • Minimum prices reduce negative externalities from consuming demerit goods
  • Tradeable pollution permits
    Limit the amount of negative externalities, in the form of pollution, created in industries, allowing firms to buy and sell allowances
  • State provision of public goods
    The government provides public goods underprovided in the free market, such as education and healthcare, which have external benefits
  • State provision of public goods can be expensive for governments and incur opportunity costs
  • Provision of information
    The government provides information to ensure no information failure, so consumers and firms can make informed decisions
  • Provision of information
    • Requiring second-hand car dealers to reveal a car's full history
  • Providing information can be expensive to police
  • Regulation
    The government uses laws to ban or mandate certain consumer or firm behaviours
  • Regulation
    • Minimum school leaving age, compulsory recycling schemes
  • Regulation can raise costs for firms who may pass them on to consumers, but fines can act as a disincentive to break rules
  • Government failure
    When government intervention worsens market failure or creates a new failure, resulting in a net welfare loss
  • Causes of government failure
    • Distortion of price signals
    • Unintended consequences
    • Excessive administrative costs
    • Information gaps
  • Government subsidies could distort price signals and lead to inefficient resource allocation
  • Unintended consequences can undermine government policies and make them expensive to implement
  • The social benefits of a policy may not be worth the financial cost of administering it
  • Lack of perfect information can lead to assumptions and poor policy decisions