judgement, decision making, reasoning

Cards (27)

  • Judgement involves deciding on the likelihood of various events
    using whatever information is available. What matters is accuracy.
  • Support theory
    • A possible future event seems more likely when it is supported by
    extra information. This is because people fail to remember all the
    relevant information when it is not explicitly mentioned.
    • The observation that we tend to overestimate the likelihood of
    information that can easily be retrieved from memory and underestimate
    the likelihood of information that is hard to retrieve is
    called the availability heuristic.
  • Base-rate information
    • People often make little or no use of base-rate information when
    making judgements. This is particularly true when they are getting
    information they have no personal experience with and when
    likelihoods are expressed as probabilities.
    • The observation that we pay too much attention to individuating
    information at the expense of base-rate information is one example
    of the use of the representativeness heuristic, the tendency we
    have to decide that an object belongs to a given category simply
    because it appears typical or representative of that category.
  • • Ignoring base-rate information can be overcome by deliberate
    thinking, which is more likely when we question a judgement
    (motivated reasoning) or when the problem formulation emphasises
    the importance of differences in base rate. Judgement also
    tends to be better when the problems are formulated in frequencies
    rather than probabilities or when visual aids are used.
  • Why do we keep using heuristics?
    • Laboratory studies have shown situations in which people are
    easily misguided by their heuristics. In daily life, however, heuristics
    are helpful most of the time.
  • • Humans seem to have a toolbox of fast and frugal heuristics that help
    them survive and cope with demands. Three of these heuristics are
    the recognition heuristic (what you recognise is more important than
    what you do not recognise), the take-the-best heuristic (go for the option that seems the best, ignore the other options), and the takethe-
    easiest heuristic (go for the option that is easier to understand).
    This, however, does not explain why humans ever developed
    deliberate judgement.
  • Dual-process model
    • According to the dual-process model, probability judgements
    depend on processing within two systems. One system is intuitive
    and fast, whereas the other is analytical and slow. We often rely
    solely on the intuitive system.
    • The dual-process model has been examined with judgement problems
    for which the System 1 answer is in conflict with the System 2
    answer. This research indicated that people seem to be sensitive to
    the conflict, even when it is not expressed in their final decisions.
    New versions of the model have been proposed to account for this
    finding.
  • Decision making involves selecting from among several possibilities.
    The quality is judged on the basis of the consequences.
  • Omission bias
    • Omission bias involves a preference for risking harm from inaction
    rather than action. It is common and has been found in medical
    experts and gamblers. It is due to anticipated responsibility and
    regret. Some individuals use the heuristic, “Don’t just sit there. Do
    something,” and show the opposite to omission bias.
  • Utility theory
    • Make choice based on benefits and cost associated w each choice
    • Prev assumed that ppl make decisions rationally, based on abstract, objective, economic principles
    • Rational decision-making = select choice that MAXIMISES EXPECTED UTILITY (value)
    • Gain as much value, avoid lesser value/chance
  • According to prospect theory, most people show loss aversion – they
    are much more sensitive to potential losses than to potential gains.
    The framing effect (in which decisions are influenced by irrelevant
    aspects of the situation) and the sunk-cost effect (in which good
    money is thrown after bad) are consistent with the theory.
  • Emotional factors
    • Our sensitivity to potential losses occurs in part because our
    emotions (especially fear) make us cautious and risk averse.
    People with damage to brain regions involved in emotional processing
    make more rational decisions. However, they do not make
    better decisions in general than healthy people. As a matter of fact,
    the reverse is true, indicating that emotions are an essential aspect
    in decision making. Emotions represent the wisdom of the ages and
    allow us in general to choose what is good for us and avoid what is
    bad for us, as argued by the somatic marker hypothesis.
  • Study context
    • Many decision-making studies are based on verbal answers to
    hypothetical problems. These decisions may differ from the actions
    people take when faced with the same dilemma in real life, as
    shown in a study with mice.
  • Social context
    • In the real world, our decision making is influenced by the social
    context and by our need to justify our decisions to other people.
    Decision making sometimes becomes more biased when there is
    increased accountability for decisions.
  • Reasoning involves drawing inferences from the knowledge we
    possess. Deductive reasoning involves drawing conclusions that
    are definitely valid (or invalid) provided that other statements
    (premises) are assumed to be true. Inductive reasoning involves
    drawing general conclusions from a sequence of observations. It
    does not guarantee valid conclusions, but generates hypotheses
    that can be tested. Both forms of reasoning are used in scientific
    research and daily life to reach conclusions.
  • Syllogistic reasoning
    • A syllogism consists of two premises or statements followed by a
    conclusion. Syllogistic reasoning is part of deductive reasoning.
    Many people make errors in syllogistic reasoning because of belief
    bias. This bias involves focusing on the believability of conclusions
    rather than their logical validity.
  • Conditional reasoning
    • Conditional reasoning is a second form of deductive reasoning.
    Many errors are made in conditional reasoning because most
    people have a limited ability to think logically and because they are influenced by irrelevant contextual information. Individuals
    high in working memory capacity perform better than those of
    low capacity.
    • Valid: Modus ponens
    • P1: A, B
    • P2: A
    • C: B (If A true, B is true)
    • Valid: Modus tollens
    • P1: A, B
    • P2: ㄱB
    • C: ㄱA (if B false, A is false)
    • Invalid: affirming the consequent, 
    • A, B
    • B
    • Therefore A (If B is true, A is true)
    • Invalid: denying the antecedent
    • A, B
    • ㄱA
    • Therefore ㄱB (If A is false, B)
  • Wason card selection task
    • Performance is generally very poor on the Wason card selection
    task because participants rely on simple strategies, such as the
    matching bias, rather than logical reasoning. Far more correct
    answers are produced when deontic rules are used because such
    rules increase participants’ attention to the possibility that the rule is
    false. Performance is also better when participants are familiar with
    the contents of the problem and are motivated to disprove the rule.
  • >>> modified task (Sperber & Girotto, 2002)
    • Use more concrete, familiar items → find task more manageable
    • Julio buys things from the Internet but is concerned he will be cheated. For each order, he fills out a card. On one side of the card, he indicates whether he has paid for the item ordered, while on the other side he indicates whether he has received the item.
  • Theories of reasoning
    • According to mental model theory, we construct mental models
    when reasoning. These models represent what is true and ignore
    what is false (principle of truth), even when what is false is relevant
    to solving the problem. Often only a single mental model is formed
    even when there are other possible mental models (principle of
    parsimony).
    • According to dual-process theory, reasoners use simple heuristic
    processes to draw inferences. Time-consuming analytic processes
    are sometimes used to revise or replace the heuristic inferences.
  • Informal reasoning
    Informal reasoning is about the probability of inferences, not about
    their truth. The content of an argument and contextual factors are
    important (unlike in deductive reasoning).
    • In informal reasoning, people are motivated to persuade others of
    their beliefs and views. Such motivation can produce errors (e.g.,
    belief bias, myside bias). However, it can also lead people to reason
    better in some situations.
  • • According to the Bayesian model of informal reasoning, the perceived
    strength of a conclusion depends on two factors: the degree
    of prior belief and the strength of the evidence. Hahn and Oaksford
    (2007) further noted that positive arguments are stronger than
    negative ones.
  • The performance of many people on reasoning problems indicates
    that their reasoning is often inadequate. However, the artificiality of
    many of the problems used means that human performance on
    many reasoning problems may underestimate our ability to think
    rationally. People spend much of their time trying to argue persuasively
    rather than to seek out the truth, and this motive can lead to
    errors in tasks on judgement and deductive reasoning.
  • At the same time, it cannot be denied that human thinking is limited
    and that this has negative consequences in life. We are rarely aware
    of these consequences because we fail to see the flaws in our
    thinking (the Dunning–Kruger effect). Research in how these flaws
    can be mediated by better information provision is ongoing.
  • When describing human rationality, it is better not to use a normative
    framework but a pragmatic framework. Within the pragmatic framework,
    Simon speaks of bounded rationality, which was extended in
    the resource-rational analysis.
  • Intelligence and rationality
    • Highly intelligent individuals perform better than those of less
    intelligence on judgement and reasoning tasks. However, the effect
    is often small.
    • According to the tripartite model, intelligent individuals may fail to
    perform well because they lack an algorithmic mind that is good
    enough to override incorrect heuristic responses, or because the
    algorithmic mind is not triggered by the reflective mind. Other
    research has indicated that the three parts of the tripartite model
    are unlikely to be independent of each other.