CHAP 16

Cards (64)

  • The Government’s Budget Constraint
    Gov Expenditure = Tax Revenue + Borrowing
  • Government expenditures must be financed by income or by borrowing
  • Government expenditure categories
    • Purchases of goods and services, G
    • Interest payments on the outstanding stock of debt (debt-service payments)
  • Debt-service payments
    Interest payments on the outstanding stock of debt (i x D)
  • Government’s net tax revenue
    Transfers included as part of T
  • Budget Deficit
    ΔD = (G + i × D) − T
  • Primary budget deficit
    The difference between the government’s overall budget deficit and its debt-service payments
  • Primary budget surplus or deficit

    Shows the extent to which current tax revenues can cover the government’s current program spending
  • Large and persistent budget deficits began in the mid-1970s and continued throughout the 1980s and early 1990s
  • The federal budget was in surplus from 1998 to 2008, but returned to deficit in 2009 mostly due to a major recession
  • The COVID-19 pandemic in 2020 led to an enormous increase in the budget deficit
  • The budget deficit increased to about 18 percent of GDP during the COVID-19 pandemic
  • Fiscal policy
    The use of government spending and tax policies
  • Changes in the budget deficit are due to changes in the government’s fiscal policy and changes in the level of economic activity
  • For a given set of expenditure and taxation policies
    The budget deficit rises as real GDP falls, and falls as real GDP rises
  • Budget deficit function
    A relationship that plots the government’s budget deficit as a function of the level of real GDP
  • Structural budget deficit
    The deficit that exists when real GDP equals Y* and expenditure and taxation policies were unchanged
  • During recessionary gaps (Y < Y*), the actual budget deficit is more than the structural budget deficit
  • During inflationary gaps (Y > Y*), the actual budget deficit is less than the structural budget deficit
  • Changes in the stance of fiscal policy are best identified by the resulting change in the structural budget deficit
  • Debt-to-GDP ratio
    The expression that relates the government budget deficit to the change in the debt-to-GDP ratio is Δd = x + (r − g) × d
  • Debt dynamics
    Two forces that tend to increase the debt-to-GDP ratio:
    - if r > g
    - if the government has a primary budget deficit
  • If the real interest rate on government debt is approximately equal to the growth rate of real GDP, reductions in the debt-to-GDP ratio require the government to run primary budget surpluses
  • Government budget deficits may crowd out private-sector activity and may harm future generations by reducing the economy’s long-run growth rate
  • Crowding out
    The offsetting reduction in private expenditure caused by the rise in interest rates that follows an expansionary fiscal policy
  • Budget surpluses may crowd in private-sector activity and be beneficial to future generations by increasing the economy’s long-run growth rate
  • In a closed economy:
    An increase in the budget deficit is assumed to cause a reduction in the supply of national saving
  • In a closed Economy:
    A reduction in the supply of national saving will increase the equilibrium real interest rate and reduce the amount of investment in the economy
  • In an open economy, the government budget deficit attracts foreign financial capital and appreciates the domestic currency
  • The long-run result of a government budget deficit is a crowding out of net exports
  • Government debt generates a redistribution of resources away from future generations toward the current generations
  • Whether there is a burden on future generations depends on the nature of the government spending being financed by the deficit
  • Debt incurred to finance public investment may result in no burden for future generations
  • Example of beneficial debt

    • The government’s financing of an electric-powered public transit network in turn reducing greenhouse gas emissions and improving mobility for the future
  • Fears of future debt monetization will likely lead to expectations of future inflation and put upward pressure on nominal interest rates and on some prices and wages
  • A large government debt may lead to the expectation of future inflation, hampering the task of the central bank in keeping inflation and inflationary expectations low
  • A large and rising stock of government debt could “tie the hands” of the government in times when it would otherwise want to conduct counter-cyclical fiscal policy
  • In January of 2020, the federal government’s debt-to-GDP ratio was about 33 percent
  • The massive increase in spending during the pandemic pushed the debt ratio up by almost 20 percentage points in a single year
  • There is support for the idea that legislation should be amended to impose restrictions on the size of budget deficits