Government expenditures must be financed by income or by borrowing
Government expenditure categories
Purchases of goods and services, G
Interest payments on the outstanding stock of debt (debt-service payments)
Debt-service payments
Interest payments on the outstanding stock of debt (i x D)
Government’s net taxrevenue
Transfers included as part of T
Budget Deficit
ΔD = (G + i × D) − T
Primary budget deficit
The difference between the government’s overall budget deficit and its debt-service payments
Primary budget surplus or deficit
Shows the extent to which current tax revenues can cover the government’s current program spending
Large and persistent budget deficits began in the mid-1970s and continued throughout the 1980s and early 1990s
The federal budget was in surplus from 1998 to 2008, but returned to deficit in 2009 mostly due to a major recession
The COVID-19 pandemic in 2020 led to an enormous increase in the budget deficit
The budget deficit increased to about 18 percent of GDP during the COVID-19 pandemic
Fiscalpolicy
The use of government spending and tax policies
Changes in the budget deficit are due to changes in the government’s fiscal policy and changes in the level of economic activity
For a given set of expenditure and taxation policies
The budget deficit rises as real GDP falls, and falls as real GDP rises
Budget deficit function
A relationship that plots the government’s budget deficit as a function of the level of real GDP
Structural budget deficit
The deficit that exists when real GDP equals Y* and expenditure and taxation policies were unchanged
During recessionary gaps (Y < Y*), the actual budget deficit is more than the structural budget deficit
During inflationary gaps (Y > Y*), the actual budget deficit is less than the structural budget deficit
Changes in the stance of fiscal policy are best identified by the resulting change in the structuralbudget deficit
Debt-to-GDP ratio
The expression that relates the government budget deficit to the change in the debt-to-GDP ratio is Δd = x + (r − g) × d
Debt dynamics
Two forces that tend to increase the debt-to-GDP ratio:
- if r > g
- if the government has a primary budget deficit
If the real interest rate on government debt is approximately equal to the growth rate of real GDP, reductions in the debt-to-GDP ratio require the government to run primary budget surpluses
Government budget deficits may crowdout private-sector activity and may harm future generations by reducing the economy’s long-run growth rate
Crowding out
The offsetting reduction in private expenditure caused by the rise in interest rates that follows an expansionary fiscal policy
Budget surpluses may crowdin private-sector activity and be beneficial to future generations by increasing the economy’s long-run growth rate
In a closed economy:
An increase in the budget deficit is assumed to cause a reduction in the supply of national saving
In a closed Economy:
A reduction in the supply of national saving will increase the equilibrium real interest rate and reduce the amount of investment in the economy
In an open economy, the government budget deficit attracts foreign financial capital and appreciates the domestic currency
The long-run result of a government budget deficit is a crowdingout of net exports
Government debt generates a redistribution of resources away from future generations toward the current generations
Whether there is a burden on future generations depends on the nature of the government spending being financed by the deficit
Debt incurred to finance public investment may result in no burden for future generations
Example of beneficial debt
The government’s financing of an electric-powered public transit network in turn reducing greenhouse gas emissions and improving mobility for the future
Fears of future debt monetization will likely lead to expectations of future inflation and put upward pressure on nominal interest rates and on some prices and wages
A large government debt may lead to the expectation of future inflation, hampering the task of the central bank in keeping inflation and inflationary expectations low
A large and rising stock of government debt could “tie the hands” of the government in times when it would otherwise want to conduct counter-cyclical fiscal policy
In January of 2020, the federal government’s debt-to-GDP ratio was about 33 percent
The massive increase in spending during the pandemic pushed the debt ratio up by almost 20 percentage points in a single year
There is support for the idea that legislation should be amended to impose restrictions on the size of budget deficits