Non-price competition in oligopoly is inherentlystrategic
Objective of non-price competition in oligopoly
To change the outcome of price and output competition favorably
Examples of non-price competition
After Sales Service
Sponsorship Deals
Brand Names
Publicity
Free Delivery
Special Features
Sales Promotion
Packaging
Advertising
Personal Selling
Commitment
A credible promise or threat
Noncredible threats or promises are not in an agents self-interest to carry though
Strategic moves
Convert threats or promises into commitment
Ways commitments can be made
Public pronouncements
Linking with an outside base
Increasing the prominence of demands
Reinforcing the threat or promise
Direct effect of strategic move
Changes the choices or payoffs of rivals
Indirect effect of strategic move
Changes the behaviors of rivals through a change in their expectations of optimal behavior
Strategic moves build a competitive advantage
Innovation
Partnership
Customer Experience
Knowledge
Cost
Strategic choices
Have long term impact, involve top level decisions
Tactical choices
Have short term impact, involve middle level decisions
Operational decisions
Involve getting tasks done
Pricing decisions are often tactical because they can be changed quickly and without incurring sunk expenditures
Decisions about non-price are often strategic because they cannot be changed quickly and involve sunk expenditures
Strategic decisions determine the choice set and payoffs of tactical decisions
Stackelberg game
A leader-follower model where the leader commits to its quantity before the follower decides how much to produce
When best response functions slope downward, the marginal revenue of a firm is decreasing in the output of its rival, so the first mover anticipates that the follower will respond to increases in output by the first mover by reducing its output
This increases the marginal revenue of the first mover relative to the Cournot game, providing it with an incentive to increase its output
The output of the leader is greater, the output of the follower is smaller, and the aggregate output greaterrelative to the Cournot game
First-mover advantage
The assumed commitment in the Stackelberg game to output by the leader provides it with a strategic advantage that leads to greater profits
The efficiency of the Stackelberg game relative to the Cournot game depends on the change in output and change in costs
Limit output
The minimum output for an incumbent required to make the profits of an entrant nonpositive
When firms produce homogenous products and there are constant returns to scale, entry deterrence is not profitable, and an incumbent will always find it more profitable to accommodate entry
When output is homogeneous and there are economies of scale, profitable entry deterrence is possible
Black-Scholes-Merton (BSM) model of limit pricing
Assumes the entrant believes the incumbent will produce the same amount after entry as before, in which case an incumbent can deter entry by producing the limit output
The Stylos Postulate is a noncredible threat: an incumbent would typically find it profit maximizing to accommodate entry by reducing output